Don’t sell. Buy! part 2

shareholderA couple of months ago I argued here in opposition to the Wall Street Flooders who are calling for investors to sell their holdings in fossil fuel companies. The flooders hope to change the business practices of those most responsible for global warming. My response was simple. Selling your stake in a company eliminates your voice in its management thereby eliminating your ability to impact its practices.

The San Francisco Chronicle is now reporting that billionaire Tom Steyer and top California democrats are planning to introduce legislation “that would require the state’s public employee pensions to sell their coal-related investments.”

I have never understood arguments in favor of divestment. When I was an undergrad, there was a very active movement calling upon universities and colleges to sell their holdings in companies doing business in South Africa. While I wholeheartedly supported the movement’s ultimate goal of ending apartheid, I never understood why selling shares of, say, Citibank to protest its presence in South Africa would modify Citibank’s behavior. After all, the profitability of the bank’s underlying ventures would be wholly unaffected and any slight drop in Citibank’s stock price would only make it more appealing to less enlightened investors.

Those who support divestment as a strategy often point to South Africa, which began to dismantle apartheid in 1990, as a success.  In fact Adele Simmons, the former President of Hampshire College, who led it to divest in 1977 wrote in support of the strategy in an op-ed for the Chicago Tribune last year.

Simmons claims that the collective withdrawal of billions of dollars invested in companies like General Motors and IBM caused them to reduce or eliminate their operations in South Africa in 1986-87.  But a close reading of her editorial strongly suggests that the two behemoths and other large multinational corporations acted because of federal legislation banning new investments and increasing violence in South Africa not because of divestment campaigns.  Simmons notes that “[d]oing business in South Africa became too expensive for American companies.”  It seems quite a stretch to link the divestiture by American institutions of their ownership stake in multinationals to increased business costs in South Africa.

A report by the Nathan Cummings Foundation confirms my view on divestment.  In Changing Corporate Behavior through Shareholder Activism, the foundation discusses, at 4-5, various ways progressive investors can seek to impact on a company’s behavior.

Investors, as the owners of a corporation, can choose one of several courses when confronted with corporate behavior they find counterproductive, whether it’s the unfettered emission of greenhouse gasses (GHGs), complicity in human rights abuses, or simply poor governance practices. They can choose to sell their stock, voice their objections to the practices in question or hold onto their stock and say nothing.

The Cummings Foundation investment managers concluded:

While selling the stock of a company with bad practices may feel ethically satisfying, it is unlikely to affect any type of significant change in corporate behavior, since when one investor sells a stock, there is, by definition, another willing to buy it.

Instead, since 2002, Cummings has engaged in active investing whereby it uses its voice as a relatively large investor in various companies:

to achieve concrete changes in corporate behavior. . . [T]he Foundation has pushed corporations to strengthen shareholder rights, improve governance practices, increase transparency and think more strategically about environmental and social issues. We’ve even been successful in prodding companies to begin reducing their GHG emissions.  Our approach of engagement instead of screening, voice instead of exit, has promoted both long-term shareholder value and the issues that the Foundation focuses on in its grantmaking.

Only extremely wealthy individuals have the financial wherewithal to buy large enough blocks of stock to impact a corporation’s direction.  But many relatively progressive institutions have billions of dollars to invest.  On their own or, even more powerfully, in concert with those of similar inclination, they can curb harmful business practices.  But any opportunity to reform a bad corporate actor is lost if the investor sells.

If Steyer and California democrats want to reduce GHG emissions they should urge large pension funds to increase, rather than liquidate, their holdings in coal extractors.  At some point, the funds may have enough leverage to push for at least some companies to transition away from production of the dirtiest of fossil fuels.

This entry was posted in Uncategorized. Bookmark the permalink.

1 Response to Don’t sell. Buy! part 2

  1. Shade says:

    Owning coal for many of us just leaves a bad taste in our mouth… and for some this is literal due to the water & other pollution that coal mining and burning creates (LOL).

    But seriously there are good reasons for a California pension fund not to invest in coal besides just the political statement it makes. The primary reason is that coal is now a declining industry & its future profitability is therefore in question.

    The coal story is not pretty, either at the mine or at the power plant. The use of coal releases more radioactivity to the environment and the food chain than nuclear accidents ever have (not to mention heavy metals & other nasties). During both mining & power plant operations, the coal industry has laid waste to huge areas of the landscape – and many of the contaminants that are dug up are only held back from potable water supplies on a temporary basis using methods that require significant sums of money each year to maintain. The coal industry is now saddled with these costs from their past years of operations and these costs don’t go away if the industry’s production now winds down. If coal production is decreased too far, the previously incurred maintenance costs from mining operations will eventually bankrupt the coal companies.

    One might argue that if the California pension funds invest in coal, this might allow the companies to morph operations into other (greener) energy sectors. This is actually true at the power plant, as coal-fired generators can generally be converted to natural gas allowing operations (and profits) to continue. However, it is another story at the coal mines themselves. To attract investments over time, increasingly coal mining companies will likely need to rely on selling high-risk, high-yield bonds. To attract investors to any newer & greener endeavors, lawyers will need to find ways to isolate the money brought in for this purpose from any potential losses that the older portions company may incur. Eventually many of the “old” coal companies as we know them will likely go bankrupt, and at that point they will leave their pollution legacy to the taxpayers as “EPA supersites”. Of course at that point their stock will be also be worthless.

    I therefore think it wise that the California employee pension funds be precluded from direct investment in the coal industry. The pension funds in question have already made poor choices & lost money chasing high yields on previous high-risk investments. Since California has never used much coal to produce its electricity, why should our state employee pension funds risk its money being lost to pay for an environmental cleanup that Californians neither created or benefited from (and that I believe is all that the coal industry will soon have to offer). Poor pension fund investments – especially when done within defined benefit plans – only leaves our state retirees more likely to require assistance from the taxpayer.

Leave a Reply to Shade Cancel reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *